Loading…

Understanding the “numbers game”

Two well-known stylized facts on earnings management are that the earnings surprise distribution has a discontinuity at zero, and that positive earnings surprises are associated with positive abnormal returns. We link these two facts in a model of the earnings management decision in which the manage...

Full description

Saved in:
Bibliographic Details
Published in:Journal of accounting & economics 2019-11, Vol.68 (2-3), p.101242, Article 101242
Main Authors: Bird, Andrew, Karolyi, Stephen A., Ruchti, Thomas G.
Format: Article
Language:English
Subjects:
Citations: Items that this one cites
Items that cite this one
Online Access:Get full text
Tags: Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
cited_by cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c342t-a168db2d314d5d298b4d940d48295bc3f1026fedb3d39aa96aba554c2165ab383
cites cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c342t-a168db2d314d5d298b4d940d48295bc3f1026fedb3d39aa96aba554c2165ab383
container_end_page
container_issue 2-3
container_start_page 101242
container_title Journal of accounting & economics
container_volume 68
creator Bird, Andrew
Karolyi, Stephen A.
Ruchti, Thomas G.
description Two well-known stylized facts on earnings management are that the earnings surprise distribution has a discontinuity at zero, and that positive earnings surprises are associated with positive abnormal returns. We link these two facts in a model of the earnings management decision in which the manager trades off the capital market benefits of meeting earnings benchmarks against the costs of manipulation. We develop a new structural methodology to estimate the model and uncover the unobserved cost function. The estimated model parameters yield the percentage of manipulating firms, magnitude of manipulation, noise in manipulation, and sufficient statistics to evaluate proxies for identifying firms suspected of manipulation. Finally, we use the Sarbanes–Oxley Act as a policy experiment and find that by increasing costs, the Act reduced equilibrium earnings management by 36%. This reduction occurred despite an increase in benefits, consistent with the market rationally becoming less skeptical of firms that just meet benchmarks. •Capital markets reward firms that just meet earnings benchmarks, and the distribution of firms jumps at the benchmark.•We model the tradeoff between the observed capital market benefits and unobserved costs of manipulating to meet benchmarks.•Estimated parameters yield the percentage of manipulating firms, the magnitude of manipulation, and noise in manipulation.•The Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduced earnings management by 36% through an increase in costs.•This occurred despite an increase in benefits, as capital markets rationally became less skeptical of benchmark-beating.
doi_str_mv 10.1016/j.jacceco.2019.101242
format article
fullrecord <record><control><sourceid>elsevier_cross</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_crossref_primary_10_1016_j_jacceco_2019_101242</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><els_id>S0165410119300370</els_id><sourcerecordid>S0165410119300370</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c342t-a168db2d314d5d298b4d940d48295bc3f1026fedb3d39aa96aba554c2165ab383</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqFj8tKxDAYhYMoWEcfQejCbcdca7ISGbzBgBtnHXL5O6bYVpIquJsH0ZebJzGls3f1w_nPOZwPoUuClwST-rpdtsY5cMOSYqImjXJ6hAoib1RFlMTHqMg-UfH8OkVnKbUYY04lLtDVpvcQ02h6H_ptOb5Bud_99J-dzWq5NR3sd7_n6KQx7wkuDneBNg_3r6unav3y-Ly6W1eOcTpWhtTSW-oZ4V54qqTlXnHsuaRKWMcagmndgLfMM2WMqo01QnBH8zZjmWQLJOZeF4eUIjT6I4bOxG9NsJ5QdasPqHpC1TNqzt3OOcjjvgJEnVyA3oEPEdyo_RD-afgDWoRf-A</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype></control><display><type>article</type><title>Understanding the “numbers game”</title><source>Elsevier</source><creator>Bird, Andrew ; Karolyi, Stephen A. ; Ruchti, Thomas G.</creator><creatorcontrib>Bird, Andrew ; Karolyi, Stephen A. ; Ruchti, Thomas G.</creatorcontrib><description>Two well-known stylized facts on earnings management are that the earnings surprise distribution has a discontinuity at zero, and that positive earnings surprises are associated with positive abnormal returns. We link these two facts in a model of the earnings management decision in which the manager trades off the capital market benefits of meeting earnings benchmarks against the costs of manipulation. We develop a new structural methodology to estimate the model and uncover the unobserved cost function. The estimated model parameters yield the percentage of manipulating firms, magnitude of manipulation, noise in manipulation, and sufficient statistics to evaluate proxies for identifying firms suspected of manipulation. Finally, we use the Sarbanes–Oxley Act as a policy experiment and find that by increasing costs, the Act reduced equilibrium earnings management by 36%. This reduction occurred despite an increase in benefits, consistent with the market rationally becoming less skeptical of firms that just meet benchmarks. •Capital markets reward firms that just meet earnings benchmarks, and the distribution of firms jumps at the benchmark.•We model the tradeoff between the observed capital market benefits and unobserved costs of manipulating to meet benchmarks.•Estimated parameters yield the percentage of manipulating firms, the magnitude of manipulation, and noise in manipulation.•The Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduced earnings management by 36% through an increase in costs.•This occurred despite an increase in benefits, as capital markets rationally became less skeptical of benchmark-beating.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0165-4101</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1879-1980</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2019.101242</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Elsevier B.V</publisher><subject>Earnings management ; Structural estimation</subject><ispartof>Journal of accounting &amp; economics, 2019-11, Vol.68 (2-3), p.101242, Article 101242</ispartof><rights>2019 Elsevier B.V.</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c342t-a168db2d314d5d298b4d940d48295bc3f1026fedb3d39aa96aba554c2165ab383</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c342t-a168db2d314d5d298b4d940d48295bc3f1026fedb3d39aa96aba554c2165ab383</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><link.rule.ids>314,780,784,27924,27925</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Bird, Andrew</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Karolyi, Stephen A.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Ruchti, Thomas G.</creatorcontrib><title>Understanding the “numbers game”</title><title>Journal of accounting &amp; economics</title><description>Two well-known stylized facts on earnings management are that the earnings surprise distribution has a discontinuity at zero, and that positive earnings surprises are associated with positive abnormal returns. We link these two facts in a model of the earnings management decision in which the manager trades off the capital market benefits of meeting earnings benchmarks against the costs of manipulation. We develop a new structural methodology to estimate the model and uncover the unobserved cost function. The estimated model parameters yield the percentage of manipulating firms, magnitude of manipulation, noise in manipulation, and sufficient statistics to evaluate proxies for identifying firms suspected of manipulation. Finally, we use the Sarbanes–Oxley Act as a policy experiment and find that by increasing costs, the Act reduced equilibrium earnings management by 36%. This reduction occurred despite an increase in benefits, consistent with the market rationally becoming less skeptical of firms that just meet benchmarks. •Capital markets reward firms that just meet earnings benchmarks, and the distribution of firms jumps at the benchmark.•We model the tradeoff between the observed capital market benefits and unobserved costs of manipulating to meet benchmarks.•Estimated parameters yield the percentage of manipulating firms, the magnitude of manipulation, and noise in manipulation.•The Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduced earnings management by 36% through an increase in costs.•This occurred despite an increase in benefits, as capital markets rationally became less skeptical of benchmark-beating.</description><subject>Earnings management</subject><subject>Structural estimation</subject><issn>0165-4101</issn><issn>1879-1980</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2019</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><recordid>eNqFj8tKxDAYhYMoWEcfQejCbcdca7ISGbzBgBtnHXL5O6bYVpIquJsH0ZebJzGls3f1w_nPOZwPoUuClwST-rpdtsY5cMOSYqImjXJ6hAoib1RFlMTHqMg-UfH8OkVnKbUYY04lLtDVpvcQ02h6H_ptOb5Bud_99J-dzWq5NR3sd7_n6KQx7wkuDneBNg_3r6unav3y-Ly6W1eOcTpWhtTSW-oZ4V54qqTlXnHsuaRKWMcagmndgLfMM2WMqo01QnBH8zZjmWQLJOZeF4eUIjT6I4bOxG9NsJ5QdasPqHpC1TNqzt3OOcjjvgJEnVyA3oEPEdyo_RD-afgDWoRf-A</recordid><startdate>201911</startdate><enddate>201911</enddate><creator>Bird, Andrew</creator><creator>Karolyi, Stephen A.</creator><creator>Ruchti, Thomas G.</creator><general>Elsevier B.V</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope></search><sort><creationdate>201911</creationdate><title>Understanding the “numbers game”</title><author>Bird, Andrew ; Karolyi, Stephen A. ; Ruchti, Thomas G.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c342t-a168db2d314d5d298b4d940d48295bc3f1026fedb3d39aa96aba554c2165ab383</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2019</creationdate><topic>Earnings management</topic><topic>Structural estimation</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Bird, Andrew</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Karolyi, Stephen A.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Ruchti, Thomas G.</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><jtitle>Journal of accounting &amp; economics</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Bird, Andrew</au><au>Karolyi, Stephen A.</au><au>Ruchti, Thomas G.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Understanding the “numbers game”</atitle><jtitle>Journal of accounting &amp; economics</jtitle><date>2019-11</date><risdate>2019</risdate><volume>68</volume><issue>2-3</issue><spage>101242</spage><pages>101242-</pages><artnum>101242</artnum><issn>0165-4101</issn><eissn>1879-1980</eissn><abstract>Two well-known stylized facts on earnings management are that the earnings surprise distribution has a discontinuity at zero, and that positive earnings surprises are associated with positive abnormal returns. We link these two facts in a model of the earnings management decision in which the manager trades off the capital market benefits of meeting earnings benchmarks against the costs of manipulation. We develop a new structural methodology to estimate the model and uncover the unobserved cost function. The estimated model parameters yield the percentage of manipulating firms, magnitude of manipulation, noise in manipulation, and sufficient statistics to evaluate proxies for identifying firms suspected of manipulation. Finally, we use the Sarbanes–Oxley Act as a policy experiment and find that by increasing costs, the Act reduced equilibrium earnings management by 36%. This reduction occurred despite an increase in benefits, consistent with the market rationally becoming less skeptical of firms that just meet benchmarks. •Capital markets reward firms that just meet earnings benchmarks, and the distribution of firms jumps at the benchmark.•We model the tradeoff between the observed capital market benefits and unobserved costs of manipulating to meet benchmarks.•Estimated parameters yield the percentage of manipulating firms, the magnitude of manipulation, and noise in manipulation.•The Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduced earnings management by 36% through an increase in costs.•This occurred despite an increase in benefits, as capital markets rationally became less skeptical of benchmark-beating.</abstract><pub>Elsevier B.V</pub><doi>10.1016/j.jacceco.2019.101242</doi></addata></record>
fulltext fulltext
identifier ISSN: 0165-4101
ispartof Journal of accounting & economics, 2019-11, Vol.68 (2-3), p.101242, Article 101242
issn 0165-4101
1879-1980
language eng
recordid cdi_crossref_primary_10_1016_j_jacceco_2019_101242
source Elsevier
subjects Earnings management
Structural estimation
title Understanding the “numbers game”
url http://sfxeu10.hosted.exlibrisgroup.com/loughborough?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-07T14%3A13%3A48IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-elsevier_cross&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Understanding%20the%20%E2%80%9Cnumbers%20game%E2%80%9D&rft.jtitle=Journal%20of%20accounting%20&%20economics&rft.au=Bird,%20Andrew&rft.date=2019-11&rft.volume=68&rft.issue=2-3&rft.spage=101242&rft.pages=101242-&rft.artnum=101242&rft.issn=0165-4101&rft.eissn=1879-1980&rft_id=info:doi/10.1016/j.jacceco.2019.101242&rft_dat=%3Celsevier_cross%3ES0165410119300370%3C/elsevier_cross%3E%3Cgrp_id%3Ecdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c342t-a168db2d314d5d298b4d940d48295bc3f1026fedb3d39aa96aba554c2165ab383%3C/grp_id%3E%3Coa%3E%3C/oa%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_id=info:pmid/&rfr_iscdi=true