Loading…

Borda count in a forward agenda

We prove that the core for Borda count is empty in many cases in which the majority core is non-empty. We then compare Borda count and majority rule in a forward agenda using a two-dimensional spatial voting model with minimal-intelligence agents who vote sincerely and propose randomly. The analysis...

Full description

Saved in:
Bibliographic Details
Published in:Public choice 2024-04, Vol.199 (1-2), p.27-44
Main Authors: Dougherty, Keith L., Ragan, Robi
Format: Article
Language:English
Subjects:
Citations: Items that this one cites
Items that cite this one
Online Access:Get full text
Tags: Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
cited_by cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c409t-44b4916f0d7b6b8c44b7df21ff14e719467ded6ed0dec3c910fdf22e0a65c5133
cites cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c409t-44b4916f0d7b6b8c44b7df21ff14e719467ded6ed0dec3c910fdf22e0a65c5133
container_end_page 44
container_issue 1-2
container_start_page 27
container_title Public choice
container_volume 199
creator Dougherty, Keith L.
Ragan, Robi
description We prove that the core for Borda count is empty in many cases in which the majority core is non-empty. We then compare Borda count and majority rule in a forward agenda using a two-dimensional spatial voting model with minimal-intelligence agents who vote sincerely and propose randomly. The analysis allows us to compare Borda count and majority rule in a dynamic setting and to show which voting rule is more capable of attaining Pareto-optimal policies and utilitarian ideals under those conditions. We find that Borda count moves policies in the rough vicinity of the Copeland winner and typically outperforms majority rule on both criteria in twenty rounds or less. Majority rule often outperforms Borda count in 1000 rounds. This provides a modest step in the application of new voting rules to committees.
doi_str_mv 10.1007/s11127-022-01037-6
format article
fullrecord <record><control><sourceid>proquest_cross</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_journals_3060075699</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><sourcerecordid>3060075699</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c409t-44b4916f0d7b6b8c44b7df21ff14e719467ded6ed0dec3c910fdf22e0a65c5133</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNp9kE9LxDAQxYMoWFe_gBcLnqMzSZo0R11cFRa86Dmk-bPsou2atIjf3mgFb56GYd57w_sRco5whQDqOiMiUxQYo4DAFZUHpMJGcaoQ8JBUAKKlTcv0MTnJeQcAXLZNRS5uh-Rt7YapH-ttX9s6DunDJl_bTei9PSVH0b7mcPY7F-Rldfe8fKDrp_vH5c2aOgF6pEJ0QqOM4FUnu9aVXfnIMEYUQaEWUvngZfDgg-NOI8RyZgGsbFyDnC_I5Zy7T8P7FPJodsOU-vLScJClYiO1Lio2q1wack4hmn3avtn0aRDMNwgzgzAFhPkBYWQx8dmUi7jfhPQX_Y_rC4kSXmo</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>3060075699</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Borda count in a forward agenda</title><source>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</source><source>Springer Nature</source><source>Worldwide Political Science Abstracts</source><creator>Dougherty, Keith L. ; Ragan, Robi</creator><creatorcontrib>Dougherty, Keith L. ; Ragan, Robi</creatorcontrib><description>We prove that the core for Borda count is empty in many cases in which the majority core is non-empty. We then compare Borda count and majority rule in a forward agenda using a two-dimensional spatial voting model with minimal-intelligence agents who vote sincerely and propose randomly. The analysis allows us to compare Borda count and majority rule in a dynamic setting and to show which voting rule is more capable of attaining Pareto-optimal policies and utilitarian ideals under those conditions. We find that Borda count moves policies in the rough vicinity of the Copeland winner and typically outperforms majority rule on both criteria in twenty rounds or less. Majority rule often outperforms Borda count in 1000 rounds. This provides a modest step in the application of new voting rules to committees.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0048-5829</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1573-7101</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1007/s11127-022-01037-6</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>New York: Springer US</publisher><subject>Committees ; Economics ; Economics and Finance ; Equilibrium ; Intelligence ; Majority rule ; Political Science ; Public Finance ; Trends ; Voters ; Voting rules</subject><ispartof>Public choice, 2024-04, Vol.199 (1-2), p.27-44</ispartof><rights>The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2023. Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c409t-44b4916f0d7b6b8c44b7df21ff14e719467ded6ed0dec3c910fdf22e0a65c5133</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c409t-44b4916f0d7b6b8c44b7df21ff14e719467ded6ed0dec3c910fdf22e0a65c5133</cites><orcidid>0000-0002-8689-1961</orcidid></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><link.rule.ids>314,777,781,27905,27906,33204</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Dougherty, Keith L.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Ragan, Robi</creatorcontrib><title>Borda count in a forward agenda</title><title>Public choice</title><addtitle>Public Choice</addtitle><description>We prove that the core for Borda count is empty in many cases in which the majority core is non-empty. We then compare Borda count and majority rule in a forward agenda using a two-dimensional spatial voting model with minimal-intelligence agents who vote sincerely and propose randomly. The analysis allows us to compare Borda count and majority rule in a dynamic setting and to show which voting rule is more capable of attaining Pareto-optimal policies and utilitarian ideals under those conditions. We find that Borda count moves policies in the rough vicinity of the Copeland winner and typically outperforms majority rule on both criteria in twenty rounds or less. Majority rule often outperforms Borda count in 1000 rounds. This provides a modest step in the application of new voting rules to committees.</description><subject>Committees</subject><subject>Economics</subject><subject>Economics and Finance</subject><subject>Equilibrium</subject><subject>Intelligence</subject><subject>Majority rule</subject><subject>Political Science</subject><subject>Public Finance</subject><subject>Trends</subject><subject>Voters</subject><subject>Voting rules</subject><issn>0048-5829</issn><issn>1573-7101</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2024</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>7UB</sourceid><sourceid>8BJ</sourceid><recordid>eNp9kE9LxDAQxYMoWFe_gBcLnqMzSZo0R11cFRa86Dmk-bPsou2atIjf3mgFb56GYd57w_sRco5whQDqOiMiUxQYo4DAFZUHpMJGcaoQ8JBUAKKlTcv0MTnJeQcAXLZNRS5uh-Rt7YapH-ttX9s6DunDJl_bTei9PSVH0b7mcPY7F-Rldfe8fKDrp_vH5c2aOgF6pEJ0QqOM4FUnu9aVXfnIMEYUQaEWUvngZfDgg-NOI8RyZgGsbFyDnC_I5Zy7T8P7FPJodsOU-vLScJClYiO1Lio2q1wack4hmn3avtn0aRDMNwgzgzAFhPkBYWQx8dmUi7jfhPQX_Y_rC4kSXmo</recordid><startdate>20240401</startdate><enddate>20240401</enddate><creator>Dougherty, Keith L.</creator><creator>Ragan, Robi</creator><general>Springer US</general><general>Springer Nature B.V</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>7UB</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope><orcidid>https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8689-1961</orcidid></search><sort><creationdate>20240401</creationdate><title>Borda count in a forward agenda</title><author>Dougherty, Keith L. ; Ragan, Robi</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c409t-44b4916f0d7b6b8c44b7df21ff14e719467ded6ed0dec3c910fdf22e0a65c5133</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2024</creationdate><topic>Committees</topic><topic>Economics</topic><topic>Economics and Finance</topic><topic>Equilibrium</topic><topic>Intelligence</topic><topic>Majority rule</topic><topic>Political Science</topic><topic>Public Finance</topic><topic>Trends</topic><topic>Voters</topic><topic>Voting rules</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Dougherty, Keith L.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Ragan, Robi</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Worldwide Political Science Abstracts</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><jtitle>Public choice</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Dougherty, Keith L.</au><au>Ragan, Robi</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Borda count in a forward agenda</atitle><jtitle>Public choice</jtitle><stitle>Public Choice</stitle><date>2024-04-01</date><risdate>2024</risdate><volume>199</volume><issue>1-2</issue><spage>27</spage><epage>44</epage><pages>27-44</pages><issn>0048-5829</issn><eissn>1573-7101</eissn><abstract>We prove that the core for Borda count is empty in many cases in which the majority core is non-empty. We then compare Borda count and majority rule in a forward agenda using a two-dimensional spatial voting model with minimal-intelligence agents who vote sincerely and propose randomly. The analysis allows us to compare Borda count and majority rule in a dynamic setting and to show which voting rule is more capable of attaining Pareto-optimal policies and utilitarian ideals under those conditions. We find that Borda count moves policies in the rough vicinity of the Copeland winner and typically outperforms majority rule on both criteria in twenty rounds or less. Majority rule often outperforms Borda count in 1000 rounds. This provides a modest step in the application of new voting rules to committees.</abstract><cop>New York</cop><pub>Springer US</pub><doi>10.1007/s11127-022-01037-6</doi><tpages>18</tpages><orcidid>https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8689-1961</orcidid></addata></record>
fulltext fulltext
identifier ISSN: 0048-5829
ispartof Public choice, 2024-04, Vol.199 (1-2), p.27-44
issn 0048-5829
1573-7101
language eng
recordid cdi_proquest_journals_3060075699
source International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS); Springer Nature; Worldwide Political Science Abstracts
subjects Committees
Economics
Economics and Finance
Equilibrium
Intelligence
Majority rule
Political Science
Public Finance
Trends
Voters
Voting rules
title Borda count in a forward agenda
url http://sfxeu10.hosted.exlibrisgroup.com/loughborough?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-19T18%3A51%3A40IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-proquest_cross&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Borda%20count%20in%20a%20forward%20agenda&rft.jtitle=Public%20choice&rft.au=Dougherty,%20Keith%20L.&rft.date=2024-04-01&rft.volume=199&rft.issue=1-2&rft.spage=27&rft.epage=44&rft.pages=27-44&rft.issn=0048-5829&rft.eissn=1573-7101&rft_id=info:doi/10.1007/s11127-022-01037-6&rft_dat=%3Cproquest_cross%3E3060075699%3C/proquest_cross%3E%3Cgrp_id%3Ecdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c409t-44b4916f0d7b6b8c44b7df21ff14e719467ded6ed0dec3c910fdf22e0a65c5133%3C/grp_id%3E%3Coa%3E%3C/oa%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=3060075699&rft_id=info:pmid/&rfr_iscdi=true