Loading…
The optimal lockdown intensity for COVID-19
One of the principal ways nations are responding to the COVID-19 pandemic is by locking down portions of their economies to reduce infectious spread. This is expensive in terms of lost jobs, lost economic productivity, and lost freedoms. So it is of interest to ask: What is the optimal intensity wit...
Saved in:
Published in: | Journal of mathematical economics 2021-03, Vol.93, p.102489-102489, Article 102489 |
---|---|
Main Authors: | , , , , , , , |
Format: | Article |
Language: | English |
Subjects: | |
Citations: | Items that this one cites Items that cite this one |
Online Access: | Get full text |
Tags: |
Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
|
cited_by | cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c594t-7615d9cb1a68c22c224554a9e1dd5ba004ad7561563dc84547f0e0decd0cda303 |
---|---|
cites | cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c594t-7615d9cb1a68c22c224554a9e1dd5ba004ad7561563dc84547f0e0decd0cda303 |
container_end_page | 102489 |
container_issue | |
container_start_page | 102489 |
container_title | Journal of mathematical economics |
container_volume | 93 |
creator | Caulkins, Jonathan P. Grass, Dieter Feichtinger, Gustav Hartl, Richard F. Kort, Peter M. Prskawetz, Alexia Seidl, Andrea Wrzaczek, Stefan |
description | One of the principal ways nations are responding to the COVID-19 pandemic is by locking down portions of their economies to reduce infectious spread. This is expensive in terms of lost jobs, lost economic productivity, and lost freedoms. So it is of interest to ask: What is the optimal intensity with which to lockdown, and how should that intensity vary dynamically over the course of an epidemic? This paper explores such questions with an optimal control model that recognizes the particular risks when infection rates surge beyond the healthcare system’s capacity to deliver appropriate care. The analysis shows that four broad strategies emerge, ranging from brief lockdowns that only “smooth the curve” to sustained lockdowns that prevent infections from spiking beyond the healthcare system’s capacity. Within this model, it can be optimal to have two separate periods of locking down, so returning to a lockdown after initial restrictions have been lifted is not necessarily a sign of failure. Relatively small changes in judgments about how to balance health and economic harms can alter dramatically which strategy prevails. Indeed, there are constellations of parameters for which two or even three of these distinct strategies can all perform equally well for the same set of initial conditions; these correspond to so-called triple Skiba points. The performance of trajectories can be highly nonlinear in the state variables, such that for various times t, the optimal unemployment rate could be low, medium, or high, but not anywhere in between. These complex dynamics emerge naturally from modeling the COVID-19 epidemic and suggest a degree of humility in policy debates. Even people who share a common understanding of the problem’s economics and epidemiology can prefer dramatically different policies. Conversely, favoring very different policies is not evident that there are fundamental disagreements. |
doi_str_mv | 10.1016/j.jmateco.2021.102489 |
format | article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>proquest_pubme</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_pubmedcentral_primary_oai_pubmedcentral_nih_gov_7857053</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><els_id>S0304406821000276</els_id><sourcerecordid>2487750131</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c594t-7615d9cb1a68c22c224554a9e1dd5ba004ad7561563dc84547f0e0decd0cda303</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqFkU9rGzEQxUVJiF0nH6FlIZdCWWe0klbaS0Nx_yQQyCXJVcjSuNZmvXKkdUq-fRTsmKaXgEAg_ebNzHuEfKIwpUDrs3barsyANkwrqGh-q7hqPpAxVZKVVDB1QMbAgJccajUiH1NqAUBKUEdkxJgQSio2Jl9vlliE9eBXpiu6YO9d-NsXvh-wT354KhYhFrPru8sfJW2OyeHCdAlPdveE3P76eTO7KK-uf1_Ovl-VVjR8KGVNhWvsnJpa2arKhwvBTYPUOTE3ANw4KTJUM2cVF1wuAMGhdWCdYcAm5NtWd72Zr9BZ7IdoOr2Oecj4pIPx-u1P75f6T3jUUgkJgmWBLzuBGB42mAa98sli15kewybpbJWUAiijGT39D23DJvZ5PV0JaBitmppnSmwpG0NKERf7YSjolzh0q3dx6Jc49DaOXPf53032Va_-Z-B8C2D289Fj1Ml67C06H9EO2gX_TotnPBOcfw</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Open Access Repository</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>2509312964</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>The optimal lockdown intensity for COVID-19</title><source>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</source><source>Backfile Package - Economics, Econometrics and Finance (Legacy) [YET]</source><source>ScienceDirect Journals</source><source>Backfile Package - Mathematics (Legacy) [YMT]</source><creator>Caulkins, Jonathan P. ; Grass, Dieter ; Feichtinger, Gustav ; Hartl, Richard F. ; Kort, Peter M. ; Prskawetz, Alexia ; Seidl, Andrea ; Wrzaczek, Stefan</creator><creatorcontrib>Caulkins, Jonathan P. ; Grass, Dieter ; Feichtinger, Gustav ; Hartl, Richard F. ; Kort, Peter M. ; Prskawetz, Alexia ; Seidl, Andrea ; Wrzaczek, Stefan</creatorcontrib><description>One of the principal ways nations are responding to the COVID-19 pandemic is by locking down portions of their economies to reduce infectious spread. This is expensive in terms of lost jobs, lost economic productivity, and lost freedoms. So it is of interest to ask: What is the optimal intensity with which to lockdown, and how should that intensity vary dynamically over the course of an epidemic? This paper explores such questions with an optimal control model that recognizes the particular risks when infection rates surge beyond the healthcare system’s capacity to deliver appropriate care. The analysis shows that four broad strategies emerge, ranging from brief lockdowns that only “smooth the curve” to sustained lockdowns that prevent infections from spiking beyond the healthcare system’s capacity. Within this model, it can be optimal to have two separate periods of locking down, so returning to a lockdown after initial restrictions have been lifted is not necessarily a sign of failure. Relatively small changes in judgments about how to balance health and economic harms can alter dramatically which strategy prevails. Indeed, there are constellations of parameters for which two or even three of these distinct strategies can all perform equally well for the same set of initial conditions; these correspond to so-called triple Skiba points. The performance of trajectories can be highly nonlinear in the state variables, such that for various times t, the optimal unemployment rate could be low, medium, or high, but not anywhere in between. These complex dynamics emerge naturally from modeling the COVID-19 epidemic and suggest a degree of humility in policy debates. Even people who share a common understanding of the problem’s economics and epidemiology can prefer dramatically different policies. Conversely, favoring very different policies is not evident that there are fundamental disagreements.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0304-4068</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1873-1538</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1016/j.jmateco.2021.102489</identifier><identifier>PMID: 33558783</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Netherlands: Elsevier B.V</publisher><subject>Constellations ; Coronaviruses ; COVID-19 ; Economic policy ; Economics ; Employment ; Epidemics ; Epidemiology ; Health care ; Health care policy ; Infections ; Initial conditions ; Lockdown ; Locking ; Optimal control ; Pandemics ; Policies ; Productivity ; Shelter in place ; SIR model ; Skiba threshold ; Unemployment ; Viral diseases</subject><ispartof>Journal of mathematical economics, 2021-03, Vol.93, p.102489-102489, Article 102489</ispartof><rights>2021 The Author(s)</rights><rights>2021 The Author(s).</rights><rights>Copyright Elsevier Sequoia S.A. Mar 2021</rights><rights>2021 The Author(s) 2021</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><oa>free_for_read</oa><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c594t-7615d9cb1a68c22c224554a9e1dd5ba004ad7561563dc84547f0e0decd0cda303</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c594t-7615d9cb1a68c22c224554a9e1dd5ba004ad7561563dc84547f0e0decd0cda303</cites><orcidid>0000-0002-7748-9989 ; 0000-0003-4882-5688 ; 0000-0002-2850-6682</orcidid></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304406821000276$$EHTML$$P50$$Gelsevier$$Hfree_for_read</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>230,314,780,784,885,3460,3564,27924,27925,33223,45992,46003</link.rule.ids><backlink>$$Uhttps://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/33558783$$D View this record in MEDLINE/PubMed$$Hfree_for_read</backlink></links><search><creatorcontrib>Caulkins, Jonathan P.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Grass, Dieter</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Feichtinger, Gustav</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Hartl, Richard F.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Kort, Peter M.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Prskawetz, Alexia</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Seidl, Andrea</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Wrzaczek, Stefan</creatorcontrib><title>The optimal lockdown intensity for COVID-19</title><title>Journal of mathematical economics</title><addtitle>J Math Econ</addtitle><description>One of the principal ways nations are responding to the COVID-19 pandemic is by locking down portions of their economies to reduce infectious spread. This is expensive in terms of lost jobs, lost economic productivity, and lost freedoms. So it is of interest to ask: What is the optimal intensity with which to lockdown, and how should that intensity vary dynamically over the course of an epidemic? This paper explores such questions with an optimal control model that recognizes the particular risks when infection rates surge beyond the healthcare system’s capacity to deliver appropriate care. The analysis shows that four broad strategies emerge, ranging from brief lockdowns that only “smooth the curve” to sustained lockdowns that prevent infections from spiking beyond the healthcare system’s capacity. Within this model, it can be optimal to have two separate periods of locking down, so returning to a lockdown after initial restrictions have been lifted is not necessarily a sign of failure. Relatively small changes in judgments about how to balance health and economic harms can alter dramatically which strategy prevails. Indeed, there are constellations of parameters for which two or even three of these distinct strategies can all perform equally well for the same set of initial conditions; these correspond to so-called triple Skiba points. The performance of trajectories can be highly nonlinear in the state variables, such that for various times t, the optimal unemployment rate could be low, medium, or high, but not anywhere in between. These complex dynamics emerge naturally from modeling the COVID-19 epidemic and suggest a degree of humility in policy debates. Even people who share a common understanding of the problem’s economics and epidemiology can prefer dramatically different policies. Conversely, favoring very different policies is not evident that there are fundamental disagreements.</description><subject>Constellations</subject><subject>Coronaviruses</subject><subject>COVID-19</subject><subject>Economic policy</subject><subject>Economics</subject><subject>Employment</subject><subject>Epidemics</subject><subject>Epidemiology</subject><subject>Health care</subject><subject>Health care policy</subject><subject>Infections</subject><subject>Initial conditions</subject><subject>Lockdown</subject><subject>Locking</subject><subject>Optimal control</subject><subject>Pandemics</subject><subject>Policies</subject><subject>Productivity</subject><subject>Shelter in place</subject><subject>SIR model</subject><subject>Skiba threshold</subject><subject>Unemployment</subject><subject>Viral diseases</subject><issn>0304-4068</issn><issn>1873-1538</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2021</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>8BJ</sourceid><recordid>eNqFkU9rGzEQxUVJiF0nH6FlIZdCWWe0klbaS0Nx_yQQyCXJVcjSuNZmvXKkdUq-fRTsmKaXgEAg_ebNzHuEfKIwpUDrs3barsyANkwrqGh-q7hqPpAxVZKVVDB1QMbAgJccajUiH1NqAUBKUEdkxJgQSio2Jl9vlliE9eBXpiu6YO9d-NsXvh-wT354KhYhFrPru8sfJW2OyeHCdAlPdveE3P76eTO7KK-uf1_Ovl-VVjR8KGVNhWvsnJpa2arKhwvBTYPUOTE3ANw4KTJUM2cVF1wuAMGhdWCdYcAm5NtWd72Zr9BZ7IdoOr2Oecj4pIPx-u1P75f6T3jUUgkJgmWBLzuBGB42mAa98sli15kewybpbJWUAiijGT39D23DJvZ5PV0JaBitmppnSmwpG0NKERf7YSjolzh0q3dx6Jc49DaOXPf53032Va_-Z-B8C2D289Fj1Ml67C06H9EO2gX_TotnPBOcfw</recordid><startdate>20210301</startdate><enddate>20210301</enddate><creator>Caulkins, Jonathan P.</creator><creator>Grass, Dieter</creator><creator>Feichtinger, Gustav</creator><creator>Hartl, Richard F.</creator><creator>Kort, Peter M.</creator><creator>Prskawetz, Alexia</creator><creator>Seidl, Andrea</creator><creator>Wrzaczek, Stefan</creator><general>Elsevier B.V</general><general>Elsevier Sequoia S.A</general><general>The Author(s). Published by Elsevier B.V</general><scope>6I.</scope><scope>AAFTH</scope><scope>NPM</scope><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope><scope>JQ2</scope><scope>7X8</scope><scope>5PM</scope><orcidid>https://orcid.org/0000-0002-7748-9989</orcidid><orcidid>https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4882-5688</orcidid><orcidid>https://orcid.org/0000-0002-2850-6682</orcidid></search><sort><creationdate>20210301</creationdate><title>The optimal lockdown intensity for COVID-19</title><author>Caulkins, Jonathan P. ; Grass, Dieter ; Feichtinger, Gustav ; Hartl, Richard F. ; Kort, Peter M. ; Prskawetz, Alexia ; Seidl, Andrea ; Wrzaczek, Stefan</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c594t-7615d9cb1a68c22c224554a9e1dd5ba004ad7561563dc84547f0e0decd0cda303</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2021</creationdate><topic>Constellations</topic><topic>Coronaviruses</topic><topic>COVID-19</topic><topic>Economic policy</topic><topic>Economics</topic><topic>Employment</topic><topic>Epidemics</topic><topic>Epidemiology</topic><topic>Health care</topic><topic>Health care policy</topic><topic>Infections</topic><topic>Initial conditions</topic><topic>Lockdown</topic><topic>Locking</topic><topic>Optimal control</topic><topic>Pandemics</topic><topic>Policies</topic><topic>Productivity</topic><topic>Shelter in place</topic><topic>SIR model</topic><topic>Skiba threshold</topic><topic>Unemployment</topic><topic>Viral diseases</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Caulkins, Jonathan P.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Grass, Dieter</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Feichtinger, Gustav</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Hartl, Richard F.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Kort, Peter M.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Prskawetz, Alexia</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Seidl, Andrea</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Wrzaczek, Stefan</creatorcontrib><collection>ScienceDirect Open Access Titles</collection><collection>Elsevier:ScienceDirect:Open Access</collection><collection>PubMed</collection><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>ProQuest Computer Science Collection</collection><collection>MEDLINE - Academic</collection><collection>PubMed Central (Full Participant titles)</collection><jtitle>Journal of mathematical economics</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Caulkins, Jonathan P.</au><au>Grass, Dieter</au><au>Feichtinger, Gustav</au><au>Hartl, Richard F.</au><au>Kort, Peter M.</au><au>Prskawetz, Alexia</au><au>Seidl, Andrea</au><au>Wrzaczek, Stefan</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>The optimal lockdown intensity for COVID-19</atitle><jtitle>Journal of mathematical economics</jtitle><addtitle>J Math Econ</addtitle><date>2021-03-01</date><risdate>2021</risdate><volume>93</volume><spage>102489</spage><epage>102489</epage><pages>102489-102489</pages><artnum>102489</artnum><issn>0304-4068</issn><eissn>1873-1538</eissn><abstract>One of the principal ways nations are responding to the COVID-19 pandemic is by locking down portions of their economies to reduce infectious spread. This is expensive in terms of lost jobs, lost economic productivity, and lost freedoms. So it is of interest to ask: What is the optimal intensity with which to lockdown, and how should that intensity vary dynamically over the course of an epidemic? This paper explores such questions with an optimal control model that recognizes the particular risks when infection rates surge beyond the healthcare system’s capacity to deliver appropriate care. The analysis shows that four broad strategies emerge, ranging from brief lockdowns that only “smooth the curve” to sustained lockdowns that prevent infections from spiking beyond the healthcare system’s capacity. Within this model, it can be optimal to have two separate periods of locking down, so returning to a lockdown after initial restrictions have been lifted is not necessarily a sign of failure. Relatively small changes in judgments about how to balance health and economic harms can alter dramatically which strategy prevails. Indeed, there are constellations of parameters for which two or even three of these distinct strategies can all perform equally well for the same set of initial conditions; these correspond to so-called triple Skiba points. The performance of trajectories can be highly nonlinear in the state variables, such that for various times t, the optimal unemployment rate could be low, medium, or high, but not anywhere in between. These complex dynamics emerge naturally from modeling the COVID-19 epidemic and suggest a degree of humility in policy debates. Even people who share a common understanding of the problem’s economics and epidemiology can prefer dramatically different policies. Conversely, favoring very different policies is not evident that there are fundamental disagreements.</abstract><cop>Netherlands</cop><pub>Elsevier B.V</pub><pmid>33558783</pmid><doi>10.1016/j.jmateco.2021.102489</doi><tpages>1</tpages><orcidid>https://orcid.org/0000-0002-7748-9989</orcidid><orcidid>https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4882-5688</orcidid><orcidid>https://orcid.org/0000-0002-2850-6682</orcidid><oa>free_for_read</oa></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0304-4068 |
ispartof | Journal of mathematical economics, 2021-03, Vol.93, p.102489-102489, Article 102489 |
issn | 0304-4068 1873-1538 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_pubmedcentral_primary_oai_pubmedcentral_nih_gov_7857053 |
source | International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS); Backfile Package - Economics, Econometrics and Finance (Legacy) [YET]; ScienceDirect Journals; Backfile Package - Mathematics (Legacy) [YMT] |
subjects | Constellations Coronaviruses COVID-19 Economic policy Economics Employment Epidemics Epidemiology Health care Health care policy Infections Initial conditions Lockdown Locking Optimal control Pandemics Policies Productivity Shelter in place SIR model Skiba threshold Unemployment Viral diseases |
title | The optimal lockdown intensity for COVID-19 |
url | http://sfxeu10.hosted.exlibrisgroup.com/loughborough?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2024-12-23T00%3A46%3A48IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-proquest_pubme&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=The%20optimal%20lockdown%20intensity%20for%20COVID-19&rft.jtitle=Journal%20of%20mathematical%20economics&rft.au=Caulkins,%20Jonathan%20P.&rft.date=2021-03-01&rft.volume=93&rft.spage=102489&rft.epage=102489&rft.pages=102489-102489&rft.artnum=102489&rft.issn=0304-4068&rft.eissn=1873-1538&rft_id=info:doi/10.1016/j.jmateco.2021.102489&rft_dat=%3Cproquest_pubme%3E2487750131%3C/proquest_pubme%3E%3Cgrp_id%3Ecdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c594t-7615d9cb1a68c22c224554a9e1dd5ba004ad7561563dc84547f0e0decd0cda303%3C/grp_id%3E%3Coa%3E%3C/oa%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=2509312964&rft_id=info:pmid/33558783&rfr_iscdi=true |